The analysus shows that even as extreme poverty has declined, wider
development gains have stalled and “income traps” remain intractable for
billions of people. The problems of these economies and a package of
policies needed to escape income traps will be discussed at a round
table on 20 July 2016 during the fourteenth session of the United
Nations Conference on Trade and Development–UNCTAD 14, the four-yearly
ministerial meeting taking place in Nairobi from 17 to 22 July 2016.
Income traps arise when the structural changes needed to speed up and
sustain economic growth as countries climb the development ladder
become increasingly challenging. But, as the experience of such
East-Asian economies as Hong Kong (China) and the Republic of Korea, and
more recently (and at lower levels of income) China and Malaysia,
shows, income traps can be avoided.
In all of these catch-up economies, albeit to varying degrees, new
production and export capacity was sequentially developed in industries
(for example, iron, steel and electronics) using skills and capabilities
transferred from existing industries, but also by the
“comparative-advantage defying” intervention of policymakers. This
strategic increase in high “connectivity” sectors allows a systematic
transition towards more sophisticated and higher value added activities
to be undertaken that eventually lead to closing productivity gaps.
Statistical analysis undertaken by UNCTAD shows that in the last 25
years, the income gap in 1990 between developing countries and the
developed member countries of the Organization for Economic Cooperation
and Development (OECD) has persisted in many cases, and in some
countries has even grown wider. It has reduced at annual rate faster
than 1 per cent in only nine economies. This highlights the lack of
convergence with leading economies.
While most economies that have experienced relatively fast
convergence come from South and South-East Asia, many countries in Latin
America, as well as in the Middle East and North Africa, have not made
much progress. Notable exceptions include Chile and Mauritius.
UNCTAD data also show that in 2014 around half of developing
countries had a per capita income lower than 15 per cent of the OECD
average. For these countries, catching up with leading economies remains
decades away even if they were able to replicate the stellar
performance of an economy such as that of the Republic of Korea.
Late-developing countries can reap “easy” productivity gains by
shifting workers from underemployment in agriculture to export-oriented
urban manufacturing but, as an economy grows richer, the pool of
underemployed rural labour will eventually be absorbed and real wages in
urban manufacturing will begin to rise.
Beyond this developmental turning point, productivity growth from
moving rural surplus labour into manufacturing needs to be replaced by
productivity growth from using better technology. Developing countries
must therefore progressively acquire the capabilities needed to develop
new products and production techniques or to adopt (and adapt) advanced
technologies developed abroad. Most of them, however, still lack the
proper institutional and production mix that would allow them to develop
or make use of knowledge-intensive products. This explains why economic
growth may suddenly come to a stop, and convergence remains unachieved.
There are five elements, according to UNCTAD, that are important for
the success of policies designed to help governments escape income
traps:
- Rents created by government policy should be made available only as a condition of enhanced performance, especially of exports and of technological upgrading. Policies designed to get out of income traps should constantly push the technology frontier by incorporating selected high-productivity projects that are more techno-logically advanced, boost skills and bring higher levels of research and development.
- The specific sectors and industries supported should vary from country to country according to their strengths and potential for upgrading, dynamic comparative advantage and impact on job creation and inequality.
- Strategic collaboration between the private sector and Government should be pursued with the objective of uncovering the potential of different sectors, identifying the most critical constraints in each of them and choosing the type of interventions most likely to succeed.
- Industrial policy should not be conceived in a vacuum but rather articulated with other development policies, using their respective instruments in a concerted fashion to maximize coherence and achieve goals.
- An effective industrial strategy depends on the creation of an appropriate structure of public and private institutions and, not least, on the development of a strong and competent public bureaucracy.
No comments:
Post a Comment